U.S. and Chile Reach Agreement on Free Trade

Free trade is firmly rooted in the American tradition of free enterprise and limited government. The Founding Fathers understood the danger of trade restrictions. Benjamin Franklin said "no nation is ever ruined by free trade." Indeed, opponents of free trade are in the position of arguing that government should pick and choose winners and losers among various types of businesses and impose itself between the buyer and seller of various goods and services, an idea completely contrary to the American ideal of individual liberty and free enterprise. The right to engage in voluntary exchange transcends national boundaries.

Trade restrictions on foreign products lower the standard of living for American consumers. Tariffs, quotas, and other trade barriers are the functional equivalent of a tax, artificially raising the cost of foreign goods and increasing the price that consumers must pay. It is estimated that these practices cost American consumers at least $70 billion per year, the equivalent of $752 per U.S. household.


Tax the poor

Moreover, the structure of trade restrictions imposes a disproportionate burden on those least able to pay. The trade restriction "tax" is a regressive one. For example, a study by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York showed that import restraints were equivalent to a 66% increase in income taxes for the poorest households, but equivalent to only a 5% tax increase for upper income households. In his book, The Fair Trade Fraud, James Bovard documents numerous examples of how import restrictions, as actually practiced, discriminate against the poor. Mink coats are duty free, while polyester baby sweaters are taxed at 34.6%; orange juice carries a 40% tariff, while Perrier water carries only a 0.8% duty.

Opponents of free trade often claim that foreign competition harms American workers. However, the evidence contradicts this claim. For example, if imports harmed domestic employment, we would expect to see unemployment rise whenever the trade deficit expands. However, an analysis of trade data for the past decade reveals that exactly the opposite appears to be true. Unemployment appears to fall even as trade deficits increase.

In addition, the cost of saving jobs through protectionism is often extremely high. For example, a 1989 study by the International Trade Commission indicated that trade protection in the glassware industry preserved 2,500 U.S. jobs. However, that protection cost U.S. consumers $185.8 million per year in the form of higher prices and reduced access to glassware. That means that every job saved cost U.S. consumers $74,320 per year. Similar calculations indicate that the 400 ceramic tile jobs saved through protectionism cost consumers $225,000 per year per job, while the 2,400 jobs saved in the rubber footwear industry cost $113,000 per year. At the very least, trade protection represents an extremely expensive form of job protection!


Domestic Jobs

However, trade protection actively harms workers because it can cost jobs. First, raising the cost of imports costs jobs in domestic industries that consume foreign goods. For example, protecting domestic sugar producers hampers the export of American candy bars. Denying American auto manufacturers access to low-cost imported steel drives up the cost of American-made cars and makes them less competitive on the world market.

U.S. protectionism also encourages other countries to raise barriers against U.S. goods. Nearly 20% of the U.S. economy is now related to foreign trade. Moreover, export-related jobs are high-paying jobs. Indeed, The Economist recently reported that "export-related jobs earn 17% more than average workers."

That a policy of unilateral free trade can lead to prosperity can be clearly seen from the example of Hong Kong. While its products are restricted by most nations (including the U.S.), Hong Kong levies no import tariffs and has few import barriers of any kind. Indeed, Hong Kong has one of the most accessible markets in the world.

As a result of this libertarian policy, the city enjoys one of the highest standards of living in Asia, rising wages, a buoyant capital market, and a rapidly growing economy.

Free trade is good for consumers, business, and American workers. And far better than any "managed trade" agreements negotiated by the government -- such as NAFTA and GATT -- would be unilateral action by the United States to reduce or eliminate tariffs, quotas, and other non-tariff barriers against foreign goods.
 
Well, *takes deep breath before saying the words that can never be taken back* I agree with S4

Free trade hurts workers in America and Canada. it also hurts workers in the other countries, like Chile. The American companies go there for cheap labour and labourers that they can exploit, and exploit them they do.

I have seen a few videos in my Labour Studies class about this very issue. It's BAD.
 
s4 said:
I really think free trade sucks, and that since Congress likes it so much they should go live in Mexico and Chile and stop milking the American People out of their livelyhoods. I think Congress sucks, too.

Ok. Flame me all you want. I don't care.

Don't worry, it is bad both ways. I'm also starting to not like the free trade stuff.

I think free trade is a good idea if it is done between "same level" nations, a good FT treaty between Mexico, Brasil and Chile would be good.
 
http://www.liberzine.com/stevenhorowitz/010506ftaa.htm


Free trade and the climb out of poverty

(I'm marking important stuff with bold)


Over the thousands of years of recorded human history, poverty and early death have been the norm, with comfort and longevity being the exceptions. The improvements in the human condition, at least on average, seen over the course of the 20th century dwarf the improvements of the previous centuries combined. By virtually any measure one can imagine, human beings are living longer, better lives than at any other time in human history.

However, there is no doubt that the wonders of the last century certainly did not touch all of humanity equally. The clear majority of the world's population, though better off than 100 years earlier, still have lives a far cry from those of even the poorest of the minority who live in the West and North. One of the most pressing questions of this century is how we can extend the bounty of last century to those who have not yet been able to enjoy fully the fruits of human improvement.

At center stage in the debate over this issue is the role of "free trade" in generating or retarding human improvement. The concern -- and protests in the streets -- over "globalization" reflects the perceived centrality of international economic activity in understanding what makes people better off. As trade across national borders continues to grow, there are those who see in that growth the attempt by Western corporations and quasi-governmental institutions such as the IMF and World Bank to extract resources from the rest of the world for their own use, leaving those who already have a long hill to climb even farther away from the top.

In addition, recent "free trade" agreements like NAFTA, and the proposed FTAA, complicate matters even more by simultaneously opening up trade and heavily regulating the trade now opened. Critics of free trade and so-called "profit-led" globalization are sometimes correct in pointing to the harmful effects of the IMF and World Bank, and the clear corporate special interests that are embodied in particular agreements. However, when those criticisms are extended to genuine free trade rightly understood, they miss the mark. Attempts to restrict such trade, or to "direct it from below," are bound to worsen the condition of those people who can afford it least. Although free trade is not sufficient to ensure economic and social well-being, it is a necessary means to that end.

The key to free trade's liberating role is that those who possess capital are able to bring that capital to workers who lack it, which in turn raises their productivity and enhances their earning power.

Underlying the argument for free trade is the principle of comparative advantage, which argues that all parties are better off when each producer does what he or she does comparatively best and trades the results with others. Specialization by comparative advantage enables each person, or state/province, or country to find what they do at least cost and to benefit from the ability to exchange for what others can produce cheaply.

Just as it makes more sense for me to specialize at being a college professor and trade for my food, clothing, and housing (rather than making it myself), it makes no sense to struggle to grow citrus in the US midwest, when residents of those states can grow grain much more cheaply and trade for citrus with Florida, which has the comparative advantage at the latter. The same principles apply across nations. When individuals are free to trade across national boundaries, producers in each area will specialize in the things they can do most cheaply, to the benefit of themselves and their trading partners.

For many third world countries, their comparative advantage is the cheapness of their labor and the availability of some natural resources. For Western firms, this presents an opportunity for profit by reducing labor and resource costs. When Western firms open up shop in the third world, they bring capital to those places. This creates jobs for citizens there, and provides the West with cheaper goods.This is the classic "mutual benefit" of all exchange: the developing country gets jobs, the home country gets cheaper goods.

The jobs created by Western firms in low-income countries average about 8 times the per capita wages of the local area, providing a significant benefit to those who take such jobs in comparison to their other options. This fact explains why people take jobs in Western-owned factories despite conditions that we in the West might find seriously unpleasant: they need to support their families and these jobs offer a much better alternative than scraping a living off the land, or collecting bottles and cans on the street, or turning to prostitution or the like.

No one is holding a gun to the heads of workers in Thailand or Indonesia when Nike or other folks come to town. They are smart enough to realize a better opportunity when they see it, and they take it. The result is the clearly observed correlation between per capita income and the degree of openness to international trade, all else equal. The increased wages of people working in Western-owned factories also makes for more demand for local products (such as food and clothing), enhancing employment opportunities and income there, causing another rise in the income-expenditure cycle elsewhere in the economy.

Meanwhile, back in the West, the cheaper imported goods enable Western consumers to have more income leftover to spend on things they otherwise would not. If my shoes cost $15 less by being made overseas, I have $15 to spend on something else. That expenditure also creates employment opportunities in the West, normally for higher-paying capital-intensive manufacturing jobs, or service-sector work.

Consider how the cheapening of food costs thanks to mechanized agriculture has enabled the Western world to have considerable excess income to spend on non-agricultural goods and a variety of services. All of those newly created jobs pay much better than the agricultural jobs displaced by mechanization. And some of those jobs may be created overseas, if the excess income is spent on other imports.

Any time that consumers can purchase goods more cheaply because producers cut costs, there follows the creation of new, better-paying, jobs elsewhere. In the last century the number of US citizens employed in agriculture dropped from about 50% of the workforce to under 3%. That change was accompanied by a tremendous increase in per-capita income (not to mention non-economic measures of well-being).

Free trade enables capital to come to those who need it most. In addition, the very profits that Western firms make in developing countries can be a long-run source of growth for those countries. Developing countries normally have very low rates of saving. Firms that operate there frequently "recycle" their profits back into investment in better technology and equipment in those countries. It is often cheaper for the firms to invest their own profits than to use formal banking institutions because the rate of indigenous savings is low and the financial institutional structure is often weak or non-existent.

Despite the claim of anti-globalization forces that free trade "puts profit before people," there is not a choice between "profits" and "people." Profits legitimately made in the market are a symbol of having created value and served people, and those same profits can be used in the future to make others better off. None of this assumes that Western firms are angelic, only self-interested. What the critics of globalization fail to recognize is that markets generate beneficial results as unintended consequences of the self-interested behavior of firms and individuals. Under a regime of free trade, self-interest is harmonized with the public interest, as the latter emerges as an unintended consequence of the former.

A further concern of many opponents of free trade and the globalization process is that it is leading to the destruction of the environment. Two points need to be made with respect to that concern.

The first is that the oft-cited "race to the bottom" is largely a myth. Environmental regulations are not one of the major factors that determine where firms locate (although very restrictive ones can push them up the list). Firms are much more concerned about secure property rights, a sound legal system, political stability, and access to communications and transportation than environmental regulations in and of themselves. The scenario where countries continually lower their standards to attract new firms is very farfetched as firms just don't put that much importance on such laws.

Second, and perhaps more important, is the overwhelming empirical evidence of what is called the Environmental Kuznets Curve. In country after country, we see a U-shaped relationship between per-capita income and environmental quality. As growth takes place, measures of environmental quality fall, but at about $5000 per-capita GDP, this turns around, with almost all categories of environmental damage showing improvement at about $8000.

Although there will be short-run costs, in the long run, the path to environmental protection is paved with economic growth. Free trade promotes that very growth, and thus will create the wealth necessary to afford clean technologies. To burden the developing world with Western-style environmental standards is to condemn its citizens to a longer stay in the very poverty they wish to escape, and would appear to replicate the very paternalistic colonialism that anti-globalization forces decry.

As former Mexican president Ernesto Zedillo put it: A peculiar alliance has recently come into life. Forces from the extreme left, the extreme right, environmentalist groups, trade unions of developed countries and some self-appointed representatives of civil society, are gathering around a common endeavor: to save the people of developing countries -- from development.

One further benefit of free trade is that it promotes international peace. Countries who trade with one another create mutual interdependence, which raises the cost of armed conflict. If one country depends on another for cheap goods and services, what gain is there to a military invasion or the like? Where interdependence is the nature of the relationship, fates are tied and war makes little sense.

International conflict flows out of the sort of nationalism that results from restrictions on free trade. Just as democracies do not go to war with other democracies, so it is that countries with open trading relationships do not go to war. Peace and free trade have a long and storied history, and the very same thinkers who have argued for free trade, and have been excoriated for it by the anti-militarist left, did so because they believed it would promote international harmony and peace.The critics of free trade need to re-read both economic history and the history of ideas and realize that their opposition to free trade is likely to increase international military activity, not reduce it.

What the critics of globalization have right, but not right enough, is the pernicious role of the IMF and World Bank. For those who support true free trade, these two institutions represent a step backward.

The critics are correct, for example, in identifying many of the ways in which they, through their loans to various governments, have caused unnecessary environmental degradation (through the inappropriate application of Western agricultural techniques over superior indigineous ones). Just as important are the ways in which the strings attached to loans and aid from those institutions lead developing countries to adopt polices antithetical to long-run development.

Many of the economic theories used by the IMF and World Bank are outdated and cause more harm than good. Moreover, they are overly focused on macroeconomic variables such as investment rates or budget deficits, when the real problems facing many developing countries are microeconomic (e.g., over-regulation of markets) or institutional (lack of well-defined property rights, politcal and legal instability, etc.). Many anti-globalization protestors argue for reforming those institutions to make them more responsive to local needs. However, such institutions will always respond to those who have political power at the national level. Rather than reforming them, advocates of truly free trade should seek to close the doors of both, and reduce the impoverishment of the developing world in the process.

Those who wish to improve the well-being of the developing world need to support the expansion of free trade. The recent agreements aimed at doing so (NAFTA and the proposed FTAA) are hardly ideal for this purpose.

Although they clearly increase the flow of goods and services across borders, they also involve a heavy dose of regulation into the process that undoes some of the benefits the trade will create. In addition, the documents are often not made public, or are so difficult to read and understand, that citizens have little idea of just how much special-interest influence has affected the final outcome. That having been said, an imperfect free trade agreement is better than none at all, and certainly better than one burdened with even more labor and environmental regulations that would prevent the developing world from taking advantage of the benefits of access to Western capital.

Finally, all sides involved in the globalization issue need to take a step back and recognize that a country's "external" policies (i.e., its policies concerning international trade and relations) are only half the equation.

Free trade is necessary but not sufficient for development. A country's "internal" policies (regulation, monetary stability, and reliable political institutions) are at least as important for economic development. A country open to international trade, but with highly restricted markets, high rates of inflation, weak legal and financial institutions, and political instability is very unlikely to grow as it is not an attractive place to go for even those who can relocate there. An agenda for encouraging the spread of wealth across all humanity should support freedom not only across national borders but within them as well.

Restrictions on free trade are no more noxious than misguided economic policies put in place by post-colonial leaders who imported those ideas from economically ill-informed Western elites. The fight to reduce human poverty must take place on many fronts.

Despite their attempts to monopolize it, the anti-globalists' views are not the only ones to lay a legitimate claim to the word "progressive." The over 200 year long attempt to open up the world to the free flow of goods, services, and people, and to make the wealth of the West available to the rest of the world, is one of the most progressive projects in human history. It has already resulted in previously unimaginable increases in wealth in those parts of the world most open to trade, and there is no reason to believe those benefits will not be extended to those who have yet to experience them.

The case for free trade is not a matter of being a corporate shill or putting profits before people. Free trade is an old and admirable policy, and one that is progressive in the truest sense -- it promises progress to all, and especially to those who need it most. Those who wish to slow down, stop, or politically control that process are the true reactionaries, standing atop the wave of human progress yelling "stop" simply because they cannot understand how an uncontrolled, spontaneously ordered, process can possibly benefit everyone.

Progress is not synonymous with intentional human control. Progress comes from good policies that let individuals use their local knowledge of time and place to their own benefit, and in doing so, unintentionally benefitting others. The path toward development requires free trade. To restrict it is to condemn to prolonged poverty those who most need to escape it.


Nixy said:
that they can exploit, and exploit them they do
You call a company offering someone a job who otherwise wouldn't have one exploitation?
 
Bubba said:
I really think free trade sucks

I've not asked in 2 years but is has become time...did you lose a job to Mexico or something? Free trade of the Americas is one of the best things that could happen to out continents. It lifts the way of life for the opressed & poor while giving the US & Canada new markets in which to expand, Win Win
 
Gonz said:
I've not asked in 2 years but is has become time...did you lose a job to Mexico or something? Free trade of the Americas is one of the best things that could happen to out continents. It lifts the way of life for the opressed & poor while giving the US & Canada new markets in which to expand, Win Win
That pretty much sums up my feelings too. Free trade is the best thing that could happen. Even with Europe. Instead, we have a little war over taxation on steel and that shit. :mad:
 
Gonz said:
Bubba said:
I really think free trade sucks

I've not asked in 2 years but is has become time...did you lose a job to Mexico or something? Free trade of the Americas is one of the best things that could happen to out continents. It lifts the way of life for the opressed & poor while giving the US & Canada new markets in which to expand, Win Win

The answer to the question is yes. I don't care to say any more than that. Perhaps, if they move the place you work to Mexico, you might not think so.

I think Bill Clinton sucks, too. He signed NAFTA in the first place.
 
Well now that you've all lost your jobs to
third world countries, can we unban CS?
 
Back
Top